Managerial Economics
CIRCULAR FLOW OF INCOME
This topic
is called 'Aggregate
demand and supply. But before we look at
these concepts, it is important that you understand the 'big picture'. The circular flow of income is a good place to start. It shows all of the money coming
into an economy (injections) and all of the money that goes out of an economy (leakages or withdrawals). It
allows you to see the 'general' reasons why an economy might grow or shrink in
size. Once you can see the 'big picture' we can then look at the specifics of aggregate demand and aggregate
supply.
The '2-sector' model
Let's start
with the simplest model. The economy is assumed to consist of only two sectors:
households and firms.
In this
very simple model of the whole economy, it is assumed that the households own
all the factors
of production. They sell these factors to the firms,
earning rent on their land, wages for the use of their labour, and profit and
interest for the use of their capital. This is shown on the left hand side of
the diagram. The green line shows the factors of production going from the
households to the firms and the red line shows the money payments by the firms
for these factors going back to the households.
The firms
then use these factors to produce goods and services. And who buys these goods
and services? The households, of course, using the income they earned from the
sale of their factors. This is shown on the right hand side of the diagram.
Again, the green line represents movements of the physical and the red line
shows the movement of the money.
Although
this model is very simple, it does emphasise one very important point. When
measuring the size of an economy, or the level of economic activity, there are
three ways of doing it. In the diagram above you can see that three of the four
moving lines have also been labelled in black. The 'rent, wages, profit and
income' branch represents total
income of the economy. The 'goods and services'
branch represents the total
output of the economy and the 'expenditure on goods
and services' branch represents the total expenditure of the economy.
So the size
of an economy can be measured using either the income, output or expenditure method. Notice that the three methods should give exactly the
same answer. It is fairly obvious that the amount of money spent must equal the
value of the goods and services that this money is spent on. Although less
obvious, it should make sense that the amount of money spent will equal the
income of the spenders, assuming that none of this income is saved. This brings
us to another key point. There are no injections into
this circularflow and no leakages from the circular flow (like saving) at this stage. Hence, Income = Output = Expenditure.
Including leakages and injections
In this
simple model, we have, so far, assumed that the system is completely closed. It
would be fair to assume, though, that households will not spend all of their
income, and that firms will, on occasion, invest in new capital.
The diagram
above has taken the first circular flow diagram a step further.The two blue
lines show savings leaking out of the economy and the injection of investment
into the economy. Where
does the saving leakage go, and where does the investment injection come from? Put very simply, savings are deposited in the banking
sector or the capital markets, and the firms borrow to invest from the same
sort of sources.
In the
first diagram, E (Expenditure) = O (Output) = Y (Income). Now there are two
types of expenditure: consumption (by households) and investment (by firms), So
E = C + I. Also, the households? income is not all spent anymore. Some of it is
saved, so Y = C + S. We
know that in equilibrium, Y = E, so by substituting we have:
Y
|
=
|
E
|
C + S
|
=
|
C + I
|
S
|
=
|
I (by
cancelling out the Cs)
|
So we can
see that in this 2-sector model, actual investment (the injection) must equal
actual saving (the leakage). It makes sense that the injections should equal
withdrawals in equilibrium. Think of the circular flow diagram as water flowing
through pipes, and the 'households' and 'firms' squares as water tanks. If
injections were greater than withdrawals, the amount of water in the system
would become infinite, which doesn't make sense. If withdrawals were greater
than injections, after a time there would be no water in the system, which also
doesn't make sense.
Although
the amount that households plan to save may not be the same as the amount that firms plan to invest, the actual amounts are always equal. If the
plans are not the same, the firms' stock levels (which count as investment)
will adjust until actual investment (planned investment plus unplanned changes
in the stock level) equals actual saving. Of course, the economy is only in an
equilibrium position if the plans are the same. Otherwise, firms will find
their stocks build up (or disappear) and change their output levels accordingly
to allow for the different saving plans (and, therefore, consumption plans) of
the households.
It does
make sense that savings equals investment. In most economies in the world, the
amount that is invested over the long term is closely related tothe amount that
the economy saves. The UK
traditionally has quite a low savings
ratio, especially when the economy is doing well,
and this has been translated into a poor record on investment over the years.
In Japan ,
the savings ration is very large. Investment is also high in Japan , as is
their investment in projects abroad.
The '3-sector' model
In the real
world, we know that there are more 'players' in an economy than simply
households and firms. The '3-sector' model includes the government sector. For
the purposes of the circular flow diagram, governments do two things: they tax
businesses and consumers, and they then spend this money on consumers (benefits
and pensions) and businesses (subsidies). The
diagram below includes the government sector.
We now have the following situation: E = C + I + G, Y = C +
S + T and Y = E in equilibrium, so:
Y
|
=
|
E
|
C + S + T
|
=
|
C + I + G
|
S + T
|
=
|
I + G (by
cancelling the Cs)
|
The
situation is a little more complicated now. We have two leakages (saving and taxation) and two injections (investment
and government spending). Now that we have a situation where actual saving does
not necessarily have to equal actual investment. Now, saving and taxation
together have to equal investment and government spending together. This means
that investment can be greater than saving as long as taxation is higher than
government spending (and vice versa).
The '4-sector' model
We are
still missing something. We have not yet included the foreign sector, or
exports and imports. Notice that in the diagram below, X denotes exports and M
denotes imports. Don't ask why, that's just the way it is!
The foreign
sector box has been added on the right of the diagram. The black line for imports
(M) comes out of the red consumption (C) line. This is because it is the
consumers who buy these imports (like German and Japanese cars) which means
that money leaks out of the economy. The injection into the economy is the
exports (X). This black line rejoins the red consumption line because exports
are consumption by foreigners of UK goods and services.
Y
|
=
|
E
|
C + S + T
+ M
|
=
|
C + I + G
+ X
|
S + T + M
|
=
|
I + G + X
(by cancelling out the Cs)
|
S, T and M
are the leakages from an economy and I, G and X are the injections into an
economy. The economy will only be in equilibrium if injections equal leakages.
You may
have seen in many textbooks the fact that National expenditure, or aggregate
planned expenditure, is equal to C + I + G + X − M. The reason why M is
included, but not S or T is that imports are a sub-group of consumption (or C).
C includes all consumption by UK
consumers, including the consumption of imports as well as home produced goods.
This has to be taken away because it is a leakage. S and T are also leakages,
but are not contained within C, I, G or X. They are separate and not part of
expenditure, so they are not included
No comments:
Post a Comment